From 1 January 2013 we face a generational change in
financial services. Personally I think a lot of this is for the good of the end
client.
Why do I think it is good for advised clients?
- It will force financial planners to have a clear
service proposition for their clients
- It will force financial planners to set a fair
charge and link that with the service proposition
- It will force financial planners to be fully
transparent with charges and fees
However what has been forgotten is that many financial
planners are already doing this. But the problems which have come from this is
that many people are being priced out of the advised market i.e. because of the
amount they have they can’t find advice.
This means they have to do it themselves and this market is
in a very complex stage adjusting to new pricing models.
If I was to identify problems with the FSAs changes it would
be the time they have taken to make some of the decisions. One of these is
around rebates. To the average person this means nothing. If you buy a pension
through say Hargreaves and invest in a fund you may pay 1.3% p.a. and assume
this is free. In reality Hargreaves are receiving a payment from the fund house
of anything from 0.5% to perhaps as high as 1%.
There is a concern that the higher the rebate they get the
more influenced they are to promote the fund. Whether they are or they are not
is one for debate but whilst you have this potential for bias there is a
danger. So to remove this bias all rebates are going to be banned.
Now you would assume this would come in from 1 January 2013
to ensure that both advised and non-advised were on a level playing field but
no potentially it is going to be 1 January 2014 and why? The reason is that the
FSA have only just made up their minds but even then haven’t agreed the final
aspects of it.
This is not about one provider outsmarting another it is
making sure everyone has a clear, fair structure to work from and I would
strongly recommend you respond to this paper.
Below is the response I sent to the FSA:
Response to
CP12/12 – Payments to platform service providers and cash rebates from
providers to consumers
Q1: Do you agree with our proposal to require a
platform service to be paid for by a platform charge disclosed to and agreed by
the client
Firstly the question is more about whether all fees
both advised and non-advised should be disclosed and the answer to this is yes.
What we have to be careful is how we see the platform. The platform is purely a
technology tool to deliver solutions or goals. It will provide different tax
efficient vehicles but it is not a product.
For an advised proposition the question is whether
the service offered by the financial planner offers value for money. It is not
about whether a typical platform offers value for money and this is an
important distinction.
If a financial planners typical package including
the “platform”, investments and advice costs 2% p.a. a year and delivers on the
client’s goals then as long as the client is fully aware of what the financial
planners charge is then they can judge whether the proposition is providing
value.
The clients are unlikely to mind about the cost of
the platform because they are not looking at this level of detail and that is
why they have a financial planner. It is however important that the platform
charge is a single fee and not different per product (i.e. some adviser led
platforms charge say 0.4% for ISA products and 0.6% for SIPP and they should
charge a flat fee of say 0.4%. Likewise you see different charging structures
for non-advised business).
If an adviser was influenced by rebates on
“platforms” either by the provider or investment house then ultimately that
would reflect in the service they provide.
For non-advised business you have a different
picture. Many non-advised platforms are seen as “free” and are advertised as
such. This makes it very difficult to compare whether paying an additional
premium for financial advice is worth the cost.
It is also clear that a small number of high
profile “free” execution only services receive large rebates up to 1% to ensure
funds are shown on their preferred list and promoted within their publications.
Although this is denied by these providers it is widely acknowledged that this
is the case within the fund distribution world. I have one example where a fund
management house admitted they were a promoting a new fund via one service
because they were guaranteed £80 million plus in new money to cede the launch
of the fund.
It is therefore important that this distortion is
removed from non-advised and advised businesses and all charges are fully
disclosed. The problem which isn’t acknowledged within the paper is the
potential complex structures already appearing in the market and this makes it
harder for people to compare.
So on one hand the requirement to disclose the
platform fee and remove any rebates is right but the danger on the flip-side is
a complex structure of charges which make it harder to uncover which
non-advised propositions offer the best value for money.
Q2: Do you
agree with our proposal that cash rebates to consumers for non-advised business
should be banned as well as those for advised business?
Looking at the advised side I believe the
assumption is wrong. Clients see the cash account as source of many things.
Ultimately it comes back to understanding that a platform is not a product but
a solution. The cash account is used as a holding place for investments, it can
be used to distribute income and it can be used for rebates to be paid into. It
is also ultimately used to pay fees, if these are paid from the investments,
and it also covers any charges the solution provider imposes.
In many cases the financial planner will always
need to ensure that there is sufficient cash within the cash account to cover
these various scenarios. The rebates do not always cover all of this and
therefore some investments will have to be sold down to cover shortfalls.
All of this comes back to the service proposition,
if the client understands the service and is fully engaged with the process
they are not worried with this level of detail. What the proposal is trying to
do is stamp out the “rogue” traders but many clients already see through this
where clients are on platforms. The problems comes were clients have old life
policies and SIPPs where this is not so clear.
To bring in a rule means you have to bring it
across to both sides of the business so both advised and non-advised. The
problem you have with non-advised is who is going to control the cash account
to cover the platform charge? I have seen recent examples where a provider has
said the £20 quarterly fee will come from non ISA cash account, then the ISA
account and if that fails the clients debit card.
Having cash rebates for both advised and non-advised
does provide a feed of money which can be used to pay the charges. Bringing a
ban brings in another layer of complexity which will make it difficult but
manageable for the advised side but potentially complex on the non-advised
side.
In summary I agree that if rebates are to be banned
they should be banned for both advised and non-advised business. However, I
believe the assumption is wrong and actually it helps the client covers fees.
The fees should be fully disclosed and if part of those can be paid for via
cash rebates then that would be better. The problem you will always have is
that some platforms may be able to demand greater rebates for clients than
others but ultimately certainly for the direct side this has to be positive for
the consumer when comparing different charges.
Do you have
any comments to make on the proposed date for implementation of 31 December
2013?
Personally I am aware that all platforms and fund
supermarkets have in place different pricing models to cope with these changes
whichever way they went. The problem is that a decision which could have been
made two years ago has been dragged on.
There should be no delay and the changes should
come in from 31 December 2012. There is evidence that non-advised platforms are
already implementing changes so others should be made to do the same.
To delay it means that where advised models have to
fully disclose their charges non-advised don’t and you start to create
confusion in the market. On the non-advised side where firms implement changes
early there is a danger that people switch to a free service only to face
charges 18 months down the road. There is already evidence that certain high
profile non-advised platforms have been targeting clients who have investments
with platforms who have adopted a transparent structure.
So a delay would not send out a good signal to the
marketplace and the changes should be adopted earlier to avoid client
confusion.
Q4: Do you
have any comments on the possible read-across of platform rules on payments for
services to non-platform markets?
There are two points here. It appears that many
non-advised and advised practitioners believe that as long as the client
remains in a fund then the rebate for that share class remains as long as they
are in that fund. For advised this will show through because of the value
proposition but for non-advised this creates a problem. Potentially it will
make those that promote funds which pay the highest rebate continue to promote
those funds to avoid clients switching out and therefore losing that valuable
payment.
It is therefore important that if cash rebates are
banned then they should be banned for existing clients as well. So effectively
a new share class is created and all clients are automatically switched into
that share class. This provides a totally level playing field between the
advised and non-advised market. The advised market will have a charge for the
platform and their service as well as the investments; the non-advised will
have a similar charging structure.
The second point is whether you should only apply
the ban on rebates to platforms and not to non-platforms. The FSA are looking
to create a clear and transparent structure. Whilst there is an imbalance
between different different solutions then you have a problem. Potentially for
non-advised business they could set up a SIPP outside of the platform and take
rebates, they could potentially argue that the SIPP is not part of the
platform. This then makes it very hard for the end customer to work out what
costs they are paying and how they compare this against other providers.
In summary a ban on rebates should go across
platforms and non-platforms and should in place from the end of December 2012.
In addition to avoid potential mispricing or double pricing it should apply
across all product solutions including SIPPs and life company products. This
will avoid launching a new transparent system which on day one has
inconsistency and confusion.
Q5: Do you
have any comments on the draft rules in Appendix 1?
The first comment is around adviser remuneration
not being obscured. The Retail Distribution Review ensures that the adviser
charge is fully disclosed. Stating that the cash rebates will obscure this is
incorrect thinking.
It goes back to the point that the rebates may pay
some of the charges but they also may be used towards income, they may be used
to pay the platform fee, they may also be used to pay the platform fee. Equally
the client could have income payments from income units coming into the cash account.
These could be used to pay fees as well. So the danger is about creating
confusion.
If as is likely you have a new share class
switching or re-registration of assets becomes more difficult because you have
an additional layer of fund classes.
The concern over distribution influence is a big
concern but I believe with RDR this removes that for financial planners because
of the requirement to fully disclose charges. For non-advised platforms this is
a big concern but unless the rebate ban is placed on existing business and
across all product types you will continue to have distribution influence
because it is in the best interest of all parties (with the exception of the
client) to keep the client in a particular share class to draw out the maximum
amount of profit.
Going forward this potentially goes for new
business on platforms but you could continue to see this where providers remove
their SIPP from the platform and continue to get rebates and distributer
influence via this route.
Effectively what this document doesn’t do is close
all the potential means by which larger providers can continue to command large
fees at the detriment of the client.
Q6: Do you
have any comments on the cost benefit analysis?
From an adviser side I have always believed
transparency is key but assuming that rebates somehow mask that is poor
thinking. If the financial planner fully discloses his fees which he should do now,
but will have to from 1 January, whether a rebate is paid or not makes no
difference.
All that happens is that you add an additional
layer of complexity where cash has to be found. The client will judge the
financial planner of the service proposition and not whether they have cash
rebates or not.
For non-advised you are creating a very complex market.
In reviewing this market recently I have seen evidence of many bringing in
quarterly fees which can be complex. So for example one charges £20 a quarter
but has a family link so it covers all family linked plans. Others charge
£11.95 but have no family link. Some allow trading charges to be taken from the
quarterly charge so effectively you have a bank. All of these pay the cash
rebates back to the clients.
The point is the cash rebate makes no difference to
some companies but what you have created is complex structures. If you don’t
ban rebates on existing funds then how are the propositions going to be priced
and how is the client going to be able to work this out. The danger is that
non-advised platforms with a lot of influence who are already encouraging
clients into funds will encourage them to stay in these funds to maximise
profit
The other problem which I have identified is that
where a quarterly fee has come into play it has priced out the lower value
savings i.e. someone saving £50 a month. These are just the people we want to
encourage to save. These people are already priced out of the advised market so
how do they save?
From an advised side the assumption is that
advisers will shop around to get the best price on fund prices and platform
prices to show their service to clients. This is very product focused. A
financial planner uses a platform as tool or solution to drive the goals. It is
not that the charges can be high but if we focus on that then we are looking at
the wrong driver for value.
There is evidence that some platforms charge one
fee for some products on their platforms and one fee for another product. If
rebates are to be banned then platforms should have a single fee irrespective
of product type. This is hinted at by the paper but should be pushed through.
So there is evidence of at least one advised platform charging 0.4% for ISA/
Non-ISA products and 0.6% for SIPP. If we take away the idea of a product and
focus on a technology driven solution then the charge should be a flat fee of
say 0.4% or 0.5%.
This is important because financial planners are
required to have a single flat fee for their service and equally technology
driven solutions should do the same. This would mean in explaining the charges
it would be easier and simpler to do, as it stands it becomes more complex.
On the non-advised side Deloitte do not see any
negative effects of bans on competition. On the non-advised side clearly the
new means of developing a solution will drive down potential margins and will
discourage people coming into the market. It states that it is unlikely to have
complex structures but the structures that are there are complex. There are
charges to transfer money away; there are penalties if the quarterly fees
aren’t paid. The banning of rebates could make the structures very complex
especially if the rebate ban is not implemented on existing business and across
SIPPs and life products.
In summary on the cost benefit analysis there are
some very dangerous assumptions. For non-advised business unless it is brought
in from 31 December 2012 and across existing plans as well as new business you
have the potential to create very complex structures. Even by bringing in the
ban you are creating complex structures but you cannot ban it on advised and
not ban on non-advised where the bias is greater. And finally you must ensure
that platforms implement a single fee for their services and not product
related fees because this adds in complexity.